Envelope theorem

Envelope theorem This article may be too technical for most readers to understand. S'il vous plaît, aidez-le à l'améliorer pour le rendre compréhensible aux non-experts, sans enlever les détails techniques. (Novembre 2021) (Découvrez comment et quand supprimer ce modèle de message) In mathematics and economics, the envelope theorem is a major result about the differentiability properties of the value function of a parameterized optimization problem.[1] As we change parameters of the objective, the envelope theorem shows that, in a certain sense, changes in the optimizer of the objective do not contribute to the change in the objective function. The envelope theorem is an important tool for comparative statics of optimization models.[2] The term envelope derives from describing the graph of the value function as the "upper envelope" of the graphs of the parameterized family of functions {style d'affichage à gauche{volé(X,cdot right)droit}_{xin X}} that are optimized.

Contenu 1 Déclaration 2 For arbitrary choice sets 3 Applications 3.1 Applications to producer theory 3.2 Applications to mechanism design and auction theory 3.3 Applications to multidimensional parameter spaces 3.4 Applications to parameterized constraints 3.5 Other applications 4 Voir également 5 References Statement Let {style d'affichage f(X,alpha )} et {style d'affichage g_{j}(X,alpha ),j=1,2,ldots ,m} be real-valued continuously differentiable functions on {style d'affichage mathbb {R} ^{n+l}} , où {style d'affichage xin mathbb {R} ^{n}} are choice variables and {displaystyle alpha in mathbb {R} ^{je}} are parameters, and consider the problem of choosing {style d'affichage x} , for a given {style d'affichage alpha } , so as to: {style d'affichage max _{X}F(X,alpha )} subject to {style d'affichage g_{j}(X,alpha )geq 0,j=1,2,ldots ,m} et {displaystyle xgeq 0} .

The Lagrangian expression of this problem is given by {style d'affichage {mathématique {L}}(X,lambda ,alpha )=f(X,alpha )+lambda cdot g(X,alpha )} où {style d'affichage lambda dans mathbb {R} ^{m}} are the Lagrange multipliers. Now let {style d'affichage x^{dernièrement }(alpha )} et {displaystyle lambda ^{dernièrement }(alpha )} together be the solution that maximizes the objective function f subject to the constraints (and hence are saddle points of the Lagrangian), {style d'affichage {mathématique {L}}^{dernièrement }(alpha )equiv f(x^{dernièrement }(alpha ),alpha )+lambda ^{dernièrement }(alpha )cdot g(x^{dernièrement }(alpha ),alpha ),} and define the value function {style d'affichage V(alpha )equiv f(x^{dernièrement }(alpha ),alpha ).} Then we have the following theorem.[3][4] Théorème: Suppose que {style d'affichage V} et {style d'affichage {mathématique {L}}} are continuously differentiable. Alors {style d'affichage {frac {partial V(alpha )}{partial alpha _{k}}}={frac {partiel {mathématique {L}}^{dernièrement }(alpha )}{partial alpha _{k}}}={frac {partiel {mathématique {L}}(x^{dernièrement }(alpha ),lambda ^{dernièrement }(alpha ),alpha )}{partial alpha _{k}}},k=1,2,ldots ,je} où {style d'affichage partiel {mathématique {L}}/partial alpha _{k}=partial f/partial alpha _{k}+lambda cdot partial g/partial alpha _{k}} .

For arbitrary choice sets Let {style d'affichage X} denote the choice set and let the relevant parameter be {displaystyle tin lbrack 0,1]} . Location {style d'affichage f:Xtimes lbrack 0,1]rightarrow R} denote the parameterized objective function, the value function {style d'affichage V} and the optimal choice correspondence (set-valued function) {style d'affichage X^{dernièrement }} are given by: {style d'affichage V(t)=sup _{xin X}F(X,t)} (1) {style d'affichage X^{dernièrement }(t)={xin X:F(X,t)=V(t)}} (2) "Envelope theorems" describe sufficient conditions for the value function {style d'affichage V} to be differentiable in the parameter {style d'affichage t} and describe its derivative as {style d'affichage V^{prime }la gauche(tright)=f_{t}la gauche(X,tright){texte{ pour chaque }}xin X^{dernièrement }la gauche(tright),} (3) où {style d'affichage f_{t}} denotes the partial derivative of {style d'affichage f} en ce qui concerne {style d'affichage t} . À savoir, the derivative of the value function with respect to the parameter equals the partial derivative of the objective function with respect to {style d'affichage t} holding the maximizer fixed at its optimal level.

Traditional envelope theorem derivations use the first-order condition for (1), which requires that the choice set {style d'affichage X} have the convex and topological structure, and the objective function {style d'affichage f} be differentiable in the variable {style d'affichage x} . (The argument is that changes in the maximizer have only a "second-order effect" at the optimum and so can be ignored.) Cependant, in many applications such as the analysis of incentive constraints in contract theory and game theory, nonconvex production problems, et "monotone" ou "robust" comparative statics, the choice sets and objective functions generally lack the topological and convexity properties required by the traditional envelope theorems.

Paul Milgrom and Segal (2002) observe that the traditional envelope formula holds for optimization problems with arbitrary choice sets at any differentiability point of the value function,[5] provided that the objective function is differentiable in the parameter: Théorème 1: Laisser {displaystyle tin left(0,1droit)} et {displaystyle xin X^{dernièrement }la gauche(tright)} . If both {style d'affichage V^{prime }la gauche(tright)} et {style d'affichage f_{t}la gauche(X,tright)} exist, the envelope formula (3) détient.

Preuve: Equation (1) implies that for {displaystyle xin X^{dernièrement }la gauche(tright)} , {style d'affichage max _{sin left[0,1droit]}la gauche[volé(X,sright)-Vleft(sright)droit]=fleft(X,tright)-Vleft(tright)=0.} Under the assumptions, the objective function of the displayed maximization problem is differentiable at {displaystyle s=t} , and the first-order condition for this maximization is exactly equation (3). Q.E.D.

While differentiability of the value function in general requires strong assumptions, in many applications weaker conditions such as absolute continuity, differentiability almost everywhere, or left- and right-differentiability, suffice. En particulier, Milgrom and Segal's (2002) Théorème 2 offers a sufficient condition for {style d'affichage V} to be absolutely continuous,[5] which means that it is differentiable almost everywhere and can be represented as an integral of its derivative: Théorème 2: Supposer que {style d'affichage f(X,cdot )} is absolutely continuous for all {style d'affichage xin X} . Suppose also that there exists an integrable function {style d'affichage b:[0,1]} {displaystyle rightarrow } {style d'affichage mathbb {R} _{+}} tel que {style d'affichage |F_{t}(X,t)|leq b(t)} pour tous {style d'affichage xin X} and almost all {displaystyle tin lbrack 0,1]} . Alors {style d'affichage V} is absolutely continuous. Supposer, en outre, ce {style d'affichage f(X,cdot )} is differentiable for all {style d'affichage xin X} , et cela {style d'affichage X^{dernièrement }(t)neq varnothing } almost everywhere on {style d'affichage [0,1]} . Then for any selection {style d'affichage x^{dernièrement }(t)en X^{dernièrement }(t)} , {style d'affichage V(t)=V(0)+entier _{0}^{t}F_{t}(x^{dernièrement }(s),s)ds.} (4) Preuve: Using (1)(1), observe that for any {displaystyle t^{prime },t ^{prime prime }in lbrack 0,1]} avec {displaystyle t^{prime }0} pour tous {displaystyle tin left[0,1droit]} . Under these assumptions, it is well known that the above constrained optimization program can be represented as a saddle-point problem for the Lagrangian {displaystyle Lleft(X,lambda ,tright)=f(X,t)+lambda cdot gleft(X,tright)} , où {style d'affichage lambda dans mathbb {R} _{+}^{K}} is the vector of Lagrange multipliers chosen by the adversary to minimize the Lagrangian.[20][page needed][21][page needed] This allows the application of Milgrom and Segal's (2002, Théorème 4) envelope theorem for saddle-point problems,[5] under the additional assumptions that {style d'affichage X} is a compact set in a normed linear space, {style d'affichage f} et {style d'affichage g} are continuous in {style d'affichage x} , et {style d'affichage f_{t}} et {style d'affichage g_{t}} are continuous in {style d'affichage à gauche(X,tright)} . En particulier, letting {style d'affichage à gauche(x^{dernièrement }(t),lambda ^{dernièrement }la gauche(tright)droit)} denote the Lagrangian's saddle point for parameter value {style d'affichage t} , the theorem implies that {style d'affichage V} is absolutely continuous and satisfies {style d'affichage V(t)=V(0)+entier _{0}^{t}L_{t}(x^{dernièrement }(s),lambda ^{dernièrement }la gauche(sright),s)ds.} For the special case in which {style d'affichage(X,tright)} is independent of {style d'affichage t} , {displaystyle K=1} , et {displaystyle gleft(X,tright)=hleft(xright)+t} , the formula implies that {style d'affichage V^{prime }(t)=L_{t}(x^{dernièrement }(t),lambda ^{dernièrement }la gauche(tright),t)=lambda ^{dernièrement }la gauche(tright)} for a.e. {style d'affichage t} . C'est-à-dire, the Lagrange multiplier {displaystyle lambda ^{dernièrement }la gauche(tright)} on the constraint is its "shadow price" in the optimization program.[21][page needed] Other applications Milgrom and Segal (2002) demonstrate that the generalized version of the envelope theorems can also be applied to convex programming, continuous optimization problems, saddle-point problems, and optimal stopping problems.[5] See also Maximum theorem Danskin's theorem Hotelling's lemma Le Chatelier's principle Roy's identity Value function References ^ Border, Kim C. (2019). "Miscellaneous Notes on Optimization Theory and Related Topics" (PDF). Lecture Notes. California Institute of Technology: 154. ^ Carter, Michael (2001). Foundations of Mathematical Economics. Cambridge: Presse du MIT. pp. 603–609. ISBN 978-0-262-53192-4. ^ Afriat, S. N. (1971). "Theory of Maxima and the Method of Lagrange". SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics. 20 (3): 343–357. est ce que je:10.1137/0120037. ^ Takayama, Akira (1985). Mathematical Economics (Deuxième éd.). New York: la presse de l'Universite de Cambridge. pp. 137–138. ISBN 978-0-521-31498-5. ^ Sauter à: a b c d e Milgrom, Paul; Ilya Segal (2002). "Envelope Theorems for Arbitrary Choice Sets". Économétrie. 70 (2): 583–601. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.217.4736. est ce que je:10.1111/1468-0262.00296. ^ Sauter à: a b Myerson, Roger (1981). "Optimal Auction Design". Mathematics of Operations Research. 6: 58–73. est ce que je:10.1287/moor.6.1.58. S2CID 12282691. ^ Mirrlees, James (2002). "An Exploration in the Theory of Optimal Taxation". Review of Economic Studies. 38 (2): 175–208. est ce que je:10.2307/2296779. JSTOR 2296779. ^ Sauter à: a b c Holmstrom, Bengt (1979). "Groves Schemes on Restricted Domains". Économétrie. 47 (5): 1137–1144. est ce que je:10.2307/1911954. JSTOR 1911954. S2CID 55414969. ^ Laffont, Jean-Jacques; Eric Maskin (1980). "A Differentiable Approach to Dominant Strategy Mechanisms". Économétrie. 48 (6): 1507–1520. est ce que je:10.2307/1912821. JSTOR 1912821. ^ Riley, John G.; Samuelson, William S. (1981). "Optimal Auctions". American Economic Review. 71 (3): 381–392. JSTOR 1802786. ^ Fudenberg, Drew; Tirole, Jean (1991). Game Theory. Cambridge: Presse du MIT. ISBN 0-262-06141-4. ^ Williams, Steven (1999). "A Characterization of Efficient, Bayesian Incentive Compatible Mechanism". Economic Theory. 14: 155–180. est ce que je:10.1007/s001990050286. S2CID 154378924. ^ Myerson, Roger (1991). Game Theory. Cambridge: Presse universitaire de Harvard. ISBN 0-674-34115-5. ^ Vert, J; Laffont, J. J. (1979). Incentives in Public Decision Making. Amsterdam: Hollande du Nord. ISBN 0-444-85144-5. ^ Myerson, R; M. Satterthwaite (1983). "Efficient Mechanisms for Bilateral Trading" (PDF). Journal de théorie économique. 29 (2): 265–281. est ce que je:10.1016/0022-0531(83)90048-0. hdl:10419/220829. ^ Jehiel, Philippe; Moldovanu, Benny (2001). "Efficient Design with Interdependent Valuations". Économétrie. 69 (5): 1237–1259. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.23.7639. est ce que je:10.1111/1468-0262.00240. ^ McAfee, R. Preston; John McMillan (1992). "Bidding Rings". American Economic Review. 82 (3): 579–599. JSTOR 2117323. ^ Weber, robert (1983). "Multiple-Object Auctions" (PDF). In Engelbrecht-Wiggans, R; Shubik, M; Rigide, R. M. (éd.). Auctions, Bidding, and Contracting: Uses and Theory. New York: New York University Press. pp. 165–191. ISBN 0-8147-7827-5. ^ Milgrom, Paul (2004). Putting Auction Theory to Work. la presse de l'Universite de Cambridge. ISBN 9780521536721. ^ Luenberger, ré. g. (1969). Optimisation par les méthodes spatiales vectorielles. New York: John Wiley & Sons. ISBN 9780471181170. ^ Sauter à: a b Rockafellar, R. J. (1970). Convex Analysis. Princeton: Presse de l'Université de Princeton. ISBN 0691015864. Catégories: Production economicsCalculus of variationsEconomics theoremsTheorems in analysis

Si vous voulez connaître d'autres articles similaires à Envelope theorem vous pouvez visiter la catégorie Calcul des variations.

Laisser un commentaire

Votre adresse email ne sera pas publiée.

Monter

Nous utilisons nos propres cookies et ceux de tiers pour améliorer l'expérience utilisateur Plus d'informations